top of page

 

Chapter V of the book The End of the Corporations

 

http://www.amazon.com/dp/1494416123   Book edition

 

http://www.amazon.com/dp/B00M6D9PHS   Kindle Edition

                                                                                           

 

 

 

 

 

 

CHAPTER V FORMS

 

“It is a well- known fact that conquest, enslavement, robbery and murder: to make it short, violence, play a protagonist role in real life history. But in the sweet political economy idyll has reined for ever… actually, the methods of original accumulation were everything but idyllic… they would resort to the power of the state, to organised and concentrated violence in society…”.

 

Karl Marx. The Capital, Vol1. Chapter XXIV   

 

 

In the face of the magnitude of the historic character of the current crisis of capitalism, it may be well worth while to stop and ask ourselves: Has capitalism ever been through crises of similar importance? In what way have these crises been overcome? What political and social phenomena spawned the crisis? And the other way round: what political and social phenomena did the crises produce?

 

In order to answer these questions it is necessary to see the current crisis from a more historical perspective and to see how the different crises and analyse how the different crises developed within their different stages and how capitalism tended to solve the contradictions that were the produce of their own development.

 

In this chapter we shall publicise and develop the General Law of Forms of Capitalist Accumulation. This law enables us to analyse applying the Marxist laws of accumulation of capital, the different forms that throughout the history of capitalism, emerged to accumulate the capital and what are the forms of accumulation characteristic for each stage of capitalism.

 

Together with the above, we shall analyse the dynamics of the Forms of accumulation the characteristic of which is the succession of phases of development and depletion linked to periods of long expansion and stagnation live throughout the history of capitalist economy.

 

Finally we shall see the political-social mechanisms that explain the way in which the transition from a lower Form of Accumulation to an upper form through the development of capitalism.          

 

 

General Law of the forms of Capitalist Accumulation

a) The Forms of Accumulation of Capital and of Predominant Forms. Definition

 

The process through which capitalists accumulate means of production on one pole in order to accumulate capital and salaries workers on the other pole, in order to accumulate more capital. As Marx explained, “…the reproduction on a broader scope in order to accumulate more capital, i.e.: accumulation reproduces capitalist relationship on a broader scope: more capitalists or greater capitalists on this pole, more salaried workers on the other… Consequently, accumulation of capital is increase of proletariat… Every individual capital is a greater or lesser concentration of means of production with the corresponding command over a larger or smaller army of workers. Every accumulation becomes a means in the service of a new accumulation…” (1)

 

The main target of capitalism is that capitalist accumulate capital and obtain profit. The necessary precondition in order to obtain this is that the means of production and exchange are to be private property, a target achieved by the capitalists by means of a historic process that placed productive, commercial firms under their control while expropriating the remaining social classes.

 

Therefore we can define Forms of Accumulation as such firms, property of the capitalist class, to accumulate capital at a determined period of time. Capitalists never used. Capitalists never used a sole form of accumulation. There have always been different forms of accumulation i.e.: different commercial, productive and financial firms acted in order to accumulate capital and they, in turn, reflect the different sectors of capitalist class. Capitalism finally imposed its rule as the dominating mode of production between the XVIII and XIX centuries, when bourgeoisie seized power in the most important countries and stamped out the remains of the feudal domination in the state. In the historic periods, when capitalism was still an embryonic element and not the dominating mode of production, as well as in the days of predominance of capitalism different Forms of Capitalist Accumulation coexisted.

 

These Forms of Accumulation developed in an uneven and combined manner hinging round a predominant Form of Accumulation that was the driving and structuring engine of economy. That is to say, when diverse Forms of Accumulation act simultaneously and at different levels of development, they hinge round the Predominant Form of accumulation and interplay with the Predominant Form of accumulation that constitutes the axis on which the entire development of capitalism is ordered.

 

Together with the concept of Forms of Accumulation, the concepts of the Regime of Accumulation, Poles of Accumulation and Axis of Accumulation are parts of the General Law of Forms of Accumulation, whose respective definitions are to be found in Chapter III. The predominant Forms of Capitalist Accumulation have been as follows:

 

                        A- At and before the stage of the original accumulation (from X to XVIII century)

 

Pre-industrial  forms of Productive accumulation

            Forms of Financial Accumulation

 

Commercial Nations (from X century to XV cen.)

            Bankers and Usury (XIV to  XVII centuries)

Factories                        (  XIV to XV century )

 

Manufactures               (   XVI to XVIII century)

 

Business Enterprises   (  XVII to XVIII  century     )

 

 

                   

                                   B- The apogee of capitalism (from XVIII century to XIX)

 

Forms of Industrial Productive Accumulations

                 Forms of financial productive Accumulation

 

Industry      (XVIII and XIX centuries)

 

                 Banks and Credit     (XVIII and XIX centuries)

  

                     

                                  C- The stage of decadence of capitalism (XIX century up to XXI century)

                 

                                            Merger of the Productive and Financial Accumulations

 

Monopolies                                    

 

        Late XIX and early XX centuries

Multinationals

        XX century (between 1945 and the 80s)

Multinational Corporations

        Late XX century up to XXI

 

 

We shall now work out a historical analysis of the different Predominant Forms of Accumulation in the different stages of capitalism,

 

             a) Forms of Accumulation specific to the stage of original accumulation

 

The first an embryonic Forms of Capitalist Accumulation began to surface between the V century and XIV century, even before the beginning of the capitalist mode of production, when the feudal mode of production still prevailed and it coexisted with the diverse modes of production and barbarian, Asiatic and even slave holder social formations.

 

The original or primeval stage of capitalism is the one when the bases for the development of capitalist production were historically established. In the early years of that stage, feudal relations of production existed in Europe and the vast majority of the population were owners of their own means of production and subsistence be that the small properties of the peasants or the great properties of the nobles.

 

During the stage of Primeval Accumulation, capitalists began to expropriate the nobles, the peasants and even sectors of capitalists. And were causing a cleavage between the producers and the means of production of which they were the owners. This spawned two phenomena: on the one hand, means of production became goods and capital the price of which was determined at the market. On the other hand the working class cropped up, that is to say the dispossessed workers, whose labour also is a commodity the price of which is determined at the market.

 

This is the way Marx explains it, “therefore, the process that creates the relation of the capital can be nothing but the process of a split between the worker and the property of his labour conditions, a process that, on the other hand, transforms the means of production and social subsistence into capital and, on the other hand, transforms direct producers into salaried workers. The so-called original accumulation is more than just a historic process of split between the producer and the means of production. It looks like “original” because it configures the prehistory of capital and the mode of production that corresponds to it.” (2)

 

The stage of the capitalist primitive accumulation affected the great rural masses more than anybody else for they were evicted from the land while traditional forms and rights of access to means of production, to natural resources, to communal rights, to pasturelands, of open countryside and so on. Between the late XV century and early XVI century, feudal retinues were dissolved in England due to violent eviction of peasants and the usurpation of communal lands by the noble lords who transformed them into pastures for cattle.

 

The second wave of expropriations was between the XVII and XVIII centuries when ecclesiastic possessions were expropriated and distributed out to the oligarchy and the peasants dwelling there were evicted. The process of the Primitive Capitalist Accumulation had some development also in the process of colonisation of all the remaining nations and continents as an outcome of the geographic discoveries in the XV and XVI centuries. This process led to ruthless annihilation of pre-capitalist civilisations and modes of production in America, Asia, Africa and Oceania and this made the expropriation of millions indigenous peoples and peoples that lived in savagery, barbarism or Asian civilisations.

 

The following Forms of Accumulation of Capital developed between the X and the XVIII centuries:

 

  1. Trading Nations; Forms of Accumulation of the trading bourgeoisie

   

 Trading nations or maritime republics that cropped up between the X and the III centuries were Forms of Capitalist Accumulation were Forms of Capitalist Accumulation whose goal was to accumulate capital practising trade based on the dominion over one or more maritime routes. These trading nations constituted an embryonic accumulation regime, with the maritime industry as the pole of accumulation. The Mediterranean was the axis of accumulation and was based on a number of cities located on what today is the territory of Italy: Amalfi, Pisa, Gaeta, Ancona, Bari, Ragusa, Noli, etc., and the powers of those days: Genoa and Venice.

 

Another regime of accumulation of the Trading Nations was located on the shores of the Baltic sea, with their axis including the cities of north of Germany and German trading communities round the Baltic Sea: Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, England, Poland, Russia, part of Finland and Denmark as well as regions where today Estonia and Latvia are to be found. This federation of cities constituted a great Nation known as Hanseatic League or Hansain the mid and late XII century and the early XIII with numerous cities in the north of Europe and surrounding the Baltic Sea: Lübeck in 1158, Rostock, Wismar, Stralsund, Greifswald, Stettin, Danzig, Ebbing, etc.

 

The name Trading Nations comes from the fact that they were enterprise-nations inasmuch as they enjoyed broad independence from the feudal authorities and an autochthonous. One or more families controlled the nation and this was what gave them the character of oligarchic republics where each one of them had its own currency, its own army, fleet, commercial colonies known as fundagos and “consuls of nations” who would watch over the commercial interests of their respective cities in the Mediterranean ports.

 

This is the way Engels explained it, “The Venetians and the Genoese in the port of Alexandria or in Constantinople, each “nation” in his own fondango residence, inn, deposit, apart from headquarters constituted complete commercial associations”. The trading nations begin their phase of emerging accompanying the expansion of European economy that was blooming in the midst of the apogee of the feudal mode of production in the X century.

 

The great surpluses and wealth of the nobles of Normandy, Burgundy, Castile, Aragon, Genoa and Venice, etc,  allowed for an important commercial circulation over the Baltic Sea as well as over the Mediterranean, and the emergence of fairs. The most important of them was Champagne on the territory of what today is France, and they acted as a commercial land bridge between the two seas. The Hansa was selling ships and even reached the Mediterranean and Italy.

 

The Trading Nations emerged from the very bowels of the Feudal system and from previous social formations, such as primitive communism. This is how Frederic Engels explains it, “the medieval merchant was in no way an individualist for he was essentially a member of some association as were all his contemporaries. In the countryside, the brand association predominated. Each peasant had his plot of land – originally of the same size… and consequently an equal share in the rights of the joint brand… And the same goes in no lesser degree for commercial associations that spawned the overseas trading… It is here that for the first time we come across profit and rate of profit… in the great commercial societies we can take it for granted that profit is distributed pro rata proportionately to the capital invested, exactly the same as the rights of the brand are distributed proportionately to the justified participation in the plot of land… Consequently, the rate of profit is the same for all.” (3)

 

Trading Nations also accumulated capital as an incipient proletariat began to develop and this is how Frederic Engels explains it, “Navigation, on the scale at which Italian and Hanseatic maritime republics practised it, would have been impossible without the assistance of sailors, i.e.: salaried workers (whose wage relation) could be concealed under corporate forms with profit sharing) just as impossible as it would have been for galleys to function without salaried or slave oarsmen. In practically all the cases, the guilds of the mines that originally consisted of associate workers had already become stock companies for the exploitation of the enterprise by means of salaried workers. And in the textile industry, the merchant had already started putting the small weaving masters directly in his service, providing them with yarn and making them transform it into cloth in consideration of a fixed wage… Here we can see the early budding of capitalist formation of surplus value” (4)

 

The Trading Nations began in the X century and achieve very high rates of profit. Just so as to be able to have a standard, let us compare the revenue of Genoa, which was one of the most important Trading Nations with France, the riches and most important monarchy in those days according to Perry Anderson, “In 1293, the maritime taxes of the port of Genoa produced three times and a half more than all the royal revenues of French monarchy” (5) The accumulated capitals were so large that they allowed the emergence and establishment of gold standard for currencies, as Perry Anderson explains it, “The maritime power of Genoa and Venice was what ensured a continuous trade surplus with Asia, a surplus that financed their return to gold… The return to gold currency in Europe in mid XIII century, with the simultaneous coinage (in 1252) of the januarius and the florin in Genoa and Florence was the resplendent symbol of commercial vitality of the cities.” (6)

 

The basis of economic expansion was the high rate of profit achieved by the Trading Nations and this is how Frederic Engels explains it, “This original rate of profit was necessarily very high…the business was monopolist trade with monopolist profit.” (7) The Trading Nations began an upward process to the apogee that included the XII and XIII centuries and produced an outstanding economic expansion in the embryonic regimes of accumulation that settled in the Mediterranean, the North Sea and the Baltic and was fed back with the economic apogee and the economic expansion of the feudal mode of production predominant in Europe with which they developed and combined.

 

The capitalists of the Trading Nations arrived at all kinds of agreements and associations of a corporative character in order to obtain jurisdictional, fiscal and customs privileges and at the same time mastery of various personal domains was achieved. During the upwards phase of Trading Nations, new exchange operations and accounting emerged, scientific discoveries were made and technologies cropped up to ensure commercial routes and to protect investments.

 

Seaworthy helmsmen were trained and lighthouses were built, compass was perfected and so were mathematics, astronomy, cartography and geography: all that in the service of navigational industry. Cities in danger of being raided by pirates organised their defence autonomously creating powerful navies to create bases, call ports and commercial establishments that influenced the political life tremendously. That is why, in the XI century Trading Nations took up the offensive and fought important wars against the Byzantine and Islamic maritime power and thus competed for the control of commerce with Asia, Africa and Mediterranean routes.

 

The Crusades allowed them to destroy the power of Islam in the Mediterranean and the Norman invasion of England put an end to the Viking incursions into the North Sea. The emerging of the rate of profit of the Trading Nations gave continuity to the equalization process of the different rates of profit a process that preceded the fall of the rate of profit and Frederic Engels explains it like that, “The equalization of these different corporative rates of profit was established by the inverse process, by competition. At the beginning, the different rates of profit (were equalised) for the different markets of the same nation… Next it was the turn for a gradual to equalize the rates of profit in the different nations that exported equal or similar good to the same markets, so quite often this or that nation would be squashed and would exit.” (8)

 

The excessive accumulation of capitals that occurred after the equalization of the rates of profit caused the rate of profit in the Trading Nations to slide down and this process was combined and re-fed with the general crisis of the feudal mode of production in the XIV century. The crisis of feudalism caused the collapse of consumption, ports were paralysed, the price of goods fell abruptly and bankruptcies became widespread. This spawned a real political, economic and social cataclysm known as the “crisis of XIV century” when nearly 40% of the population of Europe died.

 

That was the beginning of the depletion of the Trading Nations and a violent process of centralisation of capitals that led to wars for the domination over maritime routes. The depletion of Trading Nations as a Form of Accumulation, combined with the terminal crisis of the feudal mode of production caused an extremely violent process of destruction of productive forces and centralisation of capitals, the Hundred Years’ War. Together with famine and plagues, wars annihilated nations, cities entire regions. With millions dead, the Hundred Years’ War was an immense process of destruction of productive forces when capitalism was officially born.

 

Actually, the Hundred Years’ War a number of wars between nations that controlled European economy in those days and acted as the hinge between the feudal mode of production and the capitalist mode of production that emerged and started it stage of Original Accumulation. At the same time there were enormous peasant insurrections and of the workers of craft guilds in Florence or of the weavers in Ghent.

 

In the XV century, geographic discoveries accelerated the decadence of the Trading Nations, according to what Frederic Engels explained, “This process was constantly interrupted by political events while the entire Levantine commerce decayed due to the Mongolian and Turkish invasions and the great geographic-commercial discoveries carried out since 1492 did nothing but to accelerate this decadence and, later on, make it definitive.” (9)

 

The Trading Nations kept on with their decadence after the geographic discoveries in the XV and XVI centuries that became possible because of the technological development and the accumulation of capital achieved during the cycle of apogee and created means for their financing. But the geographic discoveries and the process of colonisation of Africa, Asia, America and Oceania were already stemming out of the beginnings of capitalist mode of production and its stage of primitive accumulation. As these continents were being colonised and that capitalist mode of production needed a longer period to surface and be consolidated, during the first centuries capitalists often implemented capitalist Forms of Accumulation and capitalist regimes, seeking support in non-capitalist relations of production.

 

2. Goldsmiths and silversmiths and the early Bankers. Form of Accumulation of financial bourgeoisie

 

Together with the Commercial Nations, another Form of Accumulation emerged: financial industry based on the first bankers and usurers. The great accumulation of capital that Trading Nations achieved, allowed for the increase of the numbers of capitalists dedicated to the industry linked to development and circulation of money, its transport, storing, insurance and loans. Because there was the danger of robbery, the practice of placing precious bullions and coins under the custody of goldsmiths, used to work with precious metals, receive and keep gold and silver coins for capitalists who had to store the profit obtained.

 

As this practice became more necessary, goldsmiths started charging commissions and so they were turning into bankers as they discovered when they discovered that it was not necessary to keep all the coins deposited in their vaults, so they made them circulate as loans and diverse payments while they extended receipts of deposits for the capitalists who deposited their coins and metals. The capitalist who made their deposits started using the receipts they had received from the goldsmiths to make their payments. The goldsmiths extended receipts of deposits for a higher value than that of the coins that were in their custody and in this way, the value of the money or reserve that the goldsmiths had at hand to face withdrawals in gold and silver coins represented merely a fraction of the total value or the receipts extend by them.

 

That is how the concept of banks of fractional reserve; goldsmiths and silversmiths were no longer mere guardians; they became bankers. The activity of the banks became primarily manifest in all those place where different kinds of currency circulated and this spawned moneychangers. The first banks cropped up in 1155 and were mainly devoted to traffic but they also accepted deposits and, by XIII century southern cities in Italy, like Siena and Florence, had built rudimentary banking centres.

 

In the XII century, pooled funds began to crop up as great masses of capital deposited by various capitalists who would get organised together and began to grant government borrowing to Italian cities. In Italy, these government borrowings were known as Monti, which means pool or common fund, and Bank among the Germanic peoples, which was later Italianized as Banco and the accumulation of public loans was called either Monte or Banco, which originated the use of this words for entities that accumulated capitals as deposits.

 

Bankers had connections with the Trading Nations and when smaller enterprises began to mushroom in which capitalists combined commerce with the administration of money, currencies and investments. The Fugger, the Welser, the Vöhlin, the Höchstetter, the Hirschvogel, etc are the great families of Berman bankers who, together with the Italians dominated the circulation of goods and money in those centuries in European economy, just as the Rostchild would do in the XIX century.

 

The bankers of Genoa, Florence, Venice, the Hansa as well as those from Castile, Aragon and Portugal financed the ventures of geographic discoveries of XVI and XVII centuries. These discoveries were in quest not only of new routes of navigation abut also of colonisation of new ports, exploitation of new labour and extraction of precious metals to feed the accumulation of capitals that so as to build up enough accumulation of capitals so as to finance and form the basis of money in metal as well as trust funds, indispensable accumulation to back necessary investments that allowed them to launch the capitalist mode of production.

 

This is the way Frederick Engels explained it, “But also closer partnerships associations, with more determined targets as the Genoa Manoa that controlled the mines of alum in Phocaea in Asia Minor or on the Chios Island in XIV and XV centuries or the great commercial society of Ravensburg that since the late XIV century did business with Italy and Spain, funding branches there and the German society of the Fugger, the Welser, the Vöhlin, the Höchstetter, etc from Augsburg, or the Hirschvogel of Nuremberg and others who,  with a capital of 66000 ducats and three ships who, with a capital participated in a Portuguese expedition to India between 1550-1506 and made net profit 150% according to some and 175% according to others.” (10)

 

Transition from Trading Nations to Factories

 

The first form of predominant capitalist accumulation, the Trading Nations, began the emerging phase after the Crusades starting in X Century when the allied trading powers launched numerous armed expeditions against the Muslim, the oriental Christians, Russian and Byzantine, the movement of the Cathars in the south of France and the Jews. It is estimated that the diverse slaughters and wars carried out by the crusaders caused five million deaths throughout three centuries. The process of destruction of productive forces unleashed by the struggle against the Byzantines and the Muslim allowed them to become dominant in the Mediterranean and to reach the peak of the boom phase and to control commercial exchange in the Mediterranean and with the East. During the IV Crusade (1202-1204) Venice and Genoa took over the commercially most important maritime towns of the Byzantine Empire and became the riches states in Europe.        

 

When the phase of depletion of Trading Nations began, a violent process of destruction of productive forces broke out with the wars of Pisa and Genoa in 1284, the wars of Saint Sabas in 1252 between Genoa and Venice, the war of Chioggia in 1372, the wars with the Kingdom of Hungary in 1352 apart from the wars against the Germanic Empire and the wars against the Popedom among others, while 1362 wars of the Hansa broke out against Denmark.

 

But the most important process of destruction of productive forces took place during the Hundred Years War, between the mid XIV century and mid XV, a period that was the hinge between the feudal mode of production and the capitalist one. The vicious destruction of productive forces that constituted the crisis of the XIV gave room for headway in these forms of accumulation and the process of centralisation of capitals and caused the transition of the Trading Nations to a superior for of Accumulation i.e.: Factories.

 

The destruction of productive forces in the Hundred Years’ War was centred geographically round France that was the most important economy in those days and the bastion of feudalism. The destruction of productive forces in the Hundred Years’ War was geographically centred on France that was the most important economy of those days and a bastion of feudalism. Ravaged villages, millions on the death toll, the development of technology in the industry to serve wars caused serious alterations in the prices at the market of products suffering unprecedented pressures of supply and demand. At the same time millions of peasants fought wars for their freedom and this allowed for the emerging of the first salaried workers, even if in incipient numbers.

 

In some cases, feudal lords had to yield to the pressures of their serfs in quest of their deliverance from serfdom but in other cases the insurrections were annihilated so the Hundred Years War implied a struggle between sectors of the dominating classes for control over the emerging industrial zones of greater economic importance such as Guyenne and Gascony.

 

Other wars developed similarly, among them the civil war in Normandy, The War of the Roses in England, the War between England and France, the war between France and Bourgogne, the struggle for the control over Flanders and the Netherlands, civil war in Brittany and civil wars in Castile and Aragon. In all the nations of those days, in duchies and kingdoms where wars occurred, alliances changed constantly as well as the sectors of classes whether nobles or capitalists aligned in different manners. With the development of war industry great fortunes of bankers and capitalists also cropped up financing war industry and military technology.

 

After the Hundred Years’ war, an important part of the nobility disappeared important centralisation of capitals occurred and bourgeoisie continued its ascent so the ascent of the world of cities based on trade, and the centres of power began to shift towards new burghs or cities where the new Forms of Accumulation, Factories, settled. During the decline of the Trading Nations, Portugal and the Kingdoms of Aragon and Castile developed enormous commercial activity with the geographic discoveries of XV century and this transformed them into powers even if as the last glow of the decaying Mediterranean capitalism.

 

3. Factories, A Form of Accumulation of the merchants, entrepreneurs and contractors

 

Factories are a Form of Accumulation that emerged in the XVI when capitalist merchants began to hire salaried workers in the cities as well as in the countryside. Merchant developed these ventures and became contractors since they found it cheaper to produce commodities in ports than to transport them one port to another and this allowed them to achieve important savings and profits far better than what they used to obtain with simple commercial activity.

 

According to Engels, “… there already was a rate of profit of commercial capital. What could then urge the merchants to take over the accumulative function of contractors? Only one simple thing: greater profit…” (11) Factories were based on manual work and simple cooperation, where each worker complied with a determined task without all the workers who acted on the goods grouping in the same workshop.

 

It is the capitalist himself who takes the goods from one place to another, for different workers to give them a different touch. In these techniques of industrial branches, such as textiles, goldsmithing or metallurgy productivity of labour was achieved as from the simple cooperation and manual work following the tradition of craftsmanship.

 

These Forms of Accumulation had their pole of accumulation in textile industry and mining and constituted a regime of accumulation in which the emerging industries as factories combined production and distribution with Trading Nations. The axis of accumulation was the tripod constituted by Normandy, England and the Netherlands on the Channel and the North Sea. It was precisely this geographic zone, together with France, what constituted the epicentre of the violent process of destruction of productive forces that the Hundred Years’ War implied when the dominating classes disputed the control over these incipient new industries.

 

The Hundred Years´ War expressed the emerging of a dynamic regime of accumulation as an alternative to the decadence of the regime of capitalist accumulation established in the Mediterranean. This is how Moreno explained it, “there is an extraordinary development of Mediterranean capitalism the decadence of which had already begun by the time America is discovered. Its discovery does nothing but to accelerate its decadence and the development of the new north-western capitalism that had already emerged and shifting towards the Mediterranean before the discovery of our continent. Mediterranean capitalism, impregnated with aristocratism and feudal forms, has a commercial character, usurious and international in opposition to the northeast of Europe that was manufacturing and national.” (12)

 

Factories are Forms of Accumulation where salaried labour was exploited to produce commodities and so be able to compete better with the other markets. Factories and the grouping of salaried workers is a process of exploiting salaries labour something that allowed the merchants-entrepreneurs to push the prices down so as to compete better with the other merchants who tended to adopt that form of production so as not to lose the contest for markets. Factories and the grouping of salaried workers is a process that went along 3 paths that spawned different ventures: a) privatised craftsmen’s guilds, b) domiciled rural labour and 3) privatized mining concessions. Let us analyse these three entrepreneur variants:

 

  1. Privatised craftsmen’s guilds

One of the slopes that spawned the factories was the process of privatisation of craftsmen’s guilds, industries that existed in feudalism and produced small-scale for small communities, following strict norms of production determining common targets that started turning property of capitalists.

 

Those craftsmen guilds had a pretty rigid internal organisation on three levels: masters, journeymen and apprentices-servants. Only masters were entitled to vote statutes by which the guild is to be ruled and to appoint the prosecutors and bosses. Journeymen were entitled to living quarters, food and a salary but the apprentices-servants had very low wages and remained in that state for a lifetime.

 

At first, equality and solidarity were the main traits of the guilds. Conditions of contracts and of work would vary from one guild to another and as time went by, the merchant would proceed as intermediary in the activities of the exchange of goods. Later on, regular purchase of good from the small producers became habitual and the merchant would provide small producers with raw material and would lend them money and so the small producers would fall under the economic power of the merchant.

 

Simultaneously a process of social differentiation began inside the workshops that were dominated by the masters, who were beginning to turn into owners. This accelerated the process of drifting apart of the masters and the apprentices while the former began speed up the appropriation process until they turned the guilds into companies of their property.  In turn capitalist societies emerged between commercial capitalists and craftsmen masters or the masters were expropriated by means of usury.

 

Regardless the manner, the guilds gradually became factories for they became enterprises with one or more capitalists as owners. In several cases, the power of the privatised guilds spread as far as control of municipal governments and in industries connected to exports, the master could much faster become capitalist and owner of the enterprise.

 

That is how the mediaeval craftsmanship workshops gradually disappeared and were replaced by new privatised workshops out of which the new capitalists or entrepreneurs were emerging. That is how Reyna Pastor de Togneri explains it, “handicraft corporations fall into a period of stagnation that was to last until the XVII and XVIII centuries when they vanish because they could not face up to developing capitalist forms. Organised in such a way as to increasingly benefit the masters, they will as often as not spawn new entrepreneurs.” (13)

 

  1. Rural domiciled labour

Rural domiciled labour is an enterprise that crops up because capitalist merchants would hire peasant labour to produce their goods. The merchant takes goods and raw material to peasant families’ homes and the latter will do different kinds of work such as weaving, yarning, dyeing, Peasant families combine the work they do for the capitalist and their own tasks in the fields until one by one, they fall under the control of the capitalist either out of need or because they become indebted to him.

 

That is how Reyna Pastor de Togneri explains it, “distributed the premium among the peasants” and so acquired part of their workforce… the entrepreneurs controlled the diverse processes of production and took the yarn to the fuller mills, to the dyer’s, etc. Due to this system, the peasant gradually turns into an industrial home worker who produces for the market and sells part of his workforce to the entrepreneur.” (14)

 

This kind of Factories cropped up due to the changes that took place in textile industry. For centuries, industry was based on luxurious drapery consumed by the oligarchies of Burgundy, Florence, Venice, the Papacy and Genoa, etc. But as from the beginning of the crisis of XIV, this luxurious drapery was in crisis due to the paralysis of commerce, the fall of the living standards and the decadence of nobility. Luxurious drapery included the complex technique of producing silk brought through Islam and stolen by the Crusaders.

 

Textile industry based on luxurious drapery was relegated to the background by the cheaper woollen drapery consumed by the popular classes and by the bourgeoisie supplied by the wool of sheep from England and Castile something that combined with the use of windmills in Flanders and Castile and of watermills in England, taking advantage of the enormous waterfalls in those regions; that boosted the textile industry.

 

 

According to Reyna Pastor de Togneri, rural domiciled labour was the most important enterprise of the Factories, “the importance of rural domiciled industries constituted the transitional form accrued as time went by; because of the number of employed workers, because of the amount of the production and because of the geographic area it occupies, this activity was doomed to accelerate the original accumulation of capital in the hands of merchants and bankers and also to be the one that would begin the transformations among the peasants… for it drove them away form the land, deprived them of their means of production and forced them to do routine work for long workdays and gradually turned them into salaried workers.” (15)

 

England, the place where nobility emerged much weaker after the Hundred Years´ War, where textile industry had great headway because of sheep rearing as well as because of the climate with great  waterfalls that allowed for the building of mills more fitted to drapery production, was the epicentre of rural domiciled labour. That was where ventures flourished that began to proletarianize masses of peasants and the merchants as well as the commercial capitalists could grab hold of the craftsmanship workshops much faster.

 

  1. Privatisation of mining concessions

Following a process similar to the one that the craftsmanship guilds had been through, mining concessions were appropriated by capitalists, masters’ turned-entrepreneurs, merchants trafficking metals and coins and purchasers of tin. Mining concessions were communities that signed up contracts with feudal authorities, charged a reward for the exploitation of mines and exploitation of metals and, the same as the craftsmen’s guilds; they had rules that imposed equality of the members.

 

But, as Perry Anderson explains, mining was struck by a serious crisis in the XIV century, “extraction of silver to which the entire urban and monetary sectors of feudal economy was connected ceased to be practicable or cost effective in the main mining zones of Central Europe because there was no way of opening deeper pits or of refining the more impure minerals… scarcity of metals caused repeated cases of debasement of the currency in one country after the other and consequently inflation rampant.” (16)

 

The crisis of mining exploitation together with the need for commerce to establish currencies led to increasing need of the capitalist merchants to take over mining industries and even to expand them to newly discovered and colonised territories as in the case of America, where the instauration of the system of Mita ([1]) implied enslaving tribes so far living in primitive communism.

 

The appropriation of mining concessions, the same as the appropriation of the craftsmen’s workshops by capitalist or process of their privatisation, was part of the stage of the primitive capitalist accumulation or process of privatisations for it was part of the expropriation that capitalists were carrying out on the remaining social classes. In this way, the development of various industrial branches and allowed for an incipient process of development of the working class for workshops and mining settlements mushroomed and where labour force salaried.

 

Conclusions on Factories

 

Factories started emerging in the later part of the XIV. They reached their pinnacle in late XV; this gave room for expansion of economy until early XVI. Privatised craftsmen’s guilds as well as the domiciled rural labour and the privatised mining concessions combined at that time with the budding Forms of Accumulation such as Trading Nations, banks and usury apart from the decaying feudal production.

 

Factories means headway in the centralisation and accumulation of capital and this was expressed in the importance of cities such as Flanders in textile and mining industries. But in the early XVI century, factories began their phase of depletion, economy once more became stagnant and a new violent process of destruction of productive forces occurred with the strongest points in the 80 Years’ War with epicentre in Flanders and the Dutch States in mid XVI.

 

However, the depletion of the Factories expressed not only the contradictions coming from the capitalist development, such as the levelling and falling profit rate as happened with the Trading Nations. The depletion of Factories combined economic elements with political elements as their development has been seriously limited by the existence of nobility in power, unlike the case of Trading Nations that thrived in cities, where the bourgeoisie were in power.

 

Factories are enterprises the development of which challenged the social structure of  feudalism, clashed against it and drowned in it. Bourgeoisie had to charge against the institutions that supported the feudal order and against the Catholic Church in order to be able to pass to a Superior Form of Accumulation. Wars combined the struggle for the centralisation of capitals and the struggle for power in the nations that nobility controlled and this gave Factory an unstable and transitional character.

 

Factories were not a solid Form of Accumulation as the Trading Nations were; they were rather transitional between the Medieval cottage industries that by mid XVI century were developing a crisis and the capitalist manufacturing that emerge by mid XVI century. According to Alberto J. Plá, “the qualitative leap from craftsmanship to manufacture is not simple and has an intermediate stage: that of domiciled work. But the process is slow and actually it develops by successive stages. For long periods of time, old and new forms of production coexist.” (17)

 

For nearly two centuries, Factories as industrial ventures that begin to have bourgeois owners at the steering wheel were a fundamental component of European economy and even if they were transitional enterprises, they were vital for the development of the mode of capitalist production during the stage of primitive accumulation.

 

Transition from Factories to Manufactures

 

During the Hundred Years’ Wars important changes in military industry took place: feudal knights were overridden and first professional armies appeared not joined by pact of allegiance with their lords but paid by kings and bankers and the development of new military technology. The army and the king constituted the pillar of a new regime in a feudal state. Absolute monarchy and the challenge of economic, social and political power of the nobles allowed for slow headway towards benefitting the bourgeoisie that the kings encouraged.

 

Even if most of the population was still peasant, the economic impulse and the news no longer came from the castle or the monastery but from the cities, epicentre of the development of Factories. When they started the phase of depletion, a violent process of destruction of productive forces began that allowed for a new centralisation of capitals and development of manufactures.

 

This violent development of productive forces had its epicentre in the 80 Years’ War, a complex of wars centred round the struggles of the protestant princes of Germany and the Netherlands that reflected the ascent of the bourgeoisie against the nobles of France and Spain, the strongest power in Europe in those days dominated by the nobles of Habsburg.

 

The movement of the Lutheran Reform led the process of confiscations of lands that used to belong to the Church and that was vital for the development of the textile industry. All the plot of the 80 Years’ War was a set of eight different wars that took place between 1562 and 1648 and included wars of Catholics and Calvinists when the Seventeen Provinces of the Netherlands fought against their sovereign, the king of Spain, Carlos V. Those 17 provinces sought their independence from Carlos V and Spain.

 

The rebellion of the monarchs of the Protestants was headed by Martin Luther and Calvin, but the process of destruction of the productive forces was very violent. The nobility repressed the Protestants brutally: they were persecuted and executed with great cruelty. Among those executed there were the top leader of this radical reform, Thomas Müntzer and the Spaniard Miguel Servet. After 80 years of vicious confrontations, destruction of cities and towns and millions mortal victims, the war ended with the triumph of Holland and gave room to the centralisation of capitals and that was where the United Provinces came from and achieved their independence and the bourgeoisie began their ascent and imposed a state that was modern for those days and had a Parliament with chosen representatives in all the provinces.

 

In the XVII century, the United Provinces, part of what today we call Holland and Belgium, emerged triumphant and prevailed as a world power and that turned them into one of the world centres of development of manufacturing industry together with their powerful navy and merchant fleet, This zone of Europe lived an important economic and cultural ascent as the produce of their development and expansion of Manufactures, Forms of Accumulation that were the outcome of thriving industrial development that Flanders and geographic areas comprised in the Netherlands have been enjoying since the Middle Ages, but they could clear the path as a result of the violent process of destruction of productive forces that the 80 Years´ War implied.

 

Another process of destruction of productive forces that cleared the path of Factories towards Manufactures as predominant Form of Accumulation was the annihilation of popular insurrections taking place between XIV and XV centuries due to the generalised economic an political crisis of the governments that launched vicious measures against the masses.

 

The most terrible measures were the Labour Laws that were passed in practically the entire Europe limiting the increases of wages and generalised taxes that triggered of revolts like one in maritime Flanders (123-1327) and urban Flanders (1338-1380), the French “Jacquerie” (1358), the revolution of the Ciompi in Florence (1378), the insurrection of English Tylerists or the Peasants’ Revolt (1381), the insurrection of Ghent (1372 - 1382), Hussite insurrection in the Kingdom of Hungary-Bohemia (1408 -1415), the Calabrian Insurrection (1469 -1475) and the remensa movement in Spain (1462 -1484), just top mention a few. All these insurrections and revolutions were defeated.

 

Only the beginning of the revolutionary process that allowed for the development of the Helvetic Confederation (1290-1351) could break away from this general logic of defeat. All this enormous process was simultaneous to the beginning of expropriation and genocide of millions of the native tribes, who lived in primitive communism or in Asiatic societies in America, Asia, Oceania and Africa.

 

4. Manufacturing – Form of accumulation of the manufacturing bourgeoisie

 

Manufacturing surfaces in the XVI century as the Form of Accumulation in which the capitalist groups workers in a workshop or establishment and manual work is based on the division of labour between salaried labour which exceeds simple cooperation that belongs to Factories. Each one of these workers specialises in one or two determined operations; this accrues the productivity of labour, exploitation of workers and produces cheaper commodities, which allows greater accumulation of capital and profits.

 

In manufacturing, the division of labour makes a worker achieve greater expertise, but he is no longer the producer of an accomplished commodity and so his dependence on the capitalist acquires a new and steadier character. According to Marx, “it consists in gathering workers belonging to different and independent crafts, who have to work on a product until its definite end working under the orders of a single capitalist… And as for the characteristic form… it prevails during the manufacturing period proper, which in very general lines lasts from mid XVI until the last third of XVIII.” (18)

 

There are two kinds of manufacture: the heterogeneous and the organic. We have the heterogeneous variety when we have a commodity consisting of a number of partial products that can be produced, independently and even in different workshops, and then be assembled and combined; that is the case of clocks, for example. In contrast to that, workers of different specialities are concentrated and they carry out the entire process of production up to the end and so create a determined type of commodity. Organic manufacture allows the articles to go through a series of processes, through a number of specialised workers and that the diverse phases of the process of production that used to be successive will now become simultaneous.

 

This allowed for more goods to be finished at the same time and created the premises for great industrial production, contributed for the subsequent division of labour and created the premises for the great industrial production, up to a great extent it simplified many operations, perfected the tools and prepared the means to pass on to machine production. Manufacture favoured concentration of means of production in the hands of capitalists and meant ruin for most of the craftsmen. But even though labour division in manufacturing made capitalist production of good accrue and that social work performance should grow visibly, Manufacturing did not engulf the entire social production.

 

The contrary is true. An immense number of small industrial enterprises still coexisted and that was the characteristic feature of the manufacturing period of capitalism that many Manufacturers combined their production with Factories as did the domiciled rural labour and the lingering medieval craftsmen’s workshops.

 

The role of the State in the development of Manufacturing                                    

 

State had an important role in the development of Manufacturing as can be seen in the example of France, where home market and exporting goods for markets that was known as mercantilism was the policy of Minister Colbert and Luis XIV in France. This was due to the fact that the emergence of broader home markets and a colossal growth of overseas markets produced by geographic discoveries caused extraordinary increase of the demand for goods that the development of production in those days could not satisfy.

 

Manufacture went hand-in-hand with the development of absolutist regimes in the feudal state, increasingly based on the bureaucratic state machinery, the army and the whole crowd of officials hinging round centralised and increasingly absolute power of the king. The development of the new Forms of Accumulation required from these more and more antidemocratic, brutally repressing not only of the conquered civilisations but also of the small production and the new exploited of Europe.

 

Viciously repressive institutions such as the Inquisition, witch hunts, liquidation and persecution of oppositionists, accusing of heresy any scientist or person who would reject the idea of God or of the divine authority of the King, even if these absolutist regimes conflicted with the bourgeoisie that had to impose their own state and institutions that would allow the development of their economic interests.

 

The European countries that best developed Manufacturing were England, France, Netherlands and Switzerland. In the colonised, the states established mining and industrial manufactures, as in the case of the mitas, the missions and the Encomienda ([2]) base on salaried work and slavery of the tribes and still living in primitive communism. There were also great extensions of land where work was done by tribes captured in Africa where they had been living so far and so Manufacturing was developed in the India.

 

At that time, the process of destruction of productive forces that led to manufacture consisted in veritable genocide. There is no agreement among researchers as to the numbers of Indians killed in America between the XVI and XVIII centuries but the toll can be considered as between 50 and 90 million. The system of enterprises known as encomiendas in Spain, where the Indian was supposed to be receiving a salary for his work consisted of a brutal process of exploitation tat wound up by enslaving most of the Indians who worked there.

 

Neither do researcher reach any agreement regarding the numbers of men and women captured to be sold as slaves by the XVII century in the phase of depletion of the Manufacturing, but the estimates hesitate at about 60 million Indians enslaved and distributed in 24 million in America, 12 million in Asia and 7 million in Europe while about 17 million perished during the voyages.    

       

 

This was the fate of the tribes of primitive communist tribes annihilated by the armies and navies of European states and monarchies. In Europe, the consolidation of absolutist states was based on the development of mercenary armies with great activity during the 90 Years’ War between Spain and Holland, consisting of impoverished and displaced poor noblemen, together with dispossessed peasants and craftsmen who found a job in the army.

 

The hedging in of lands have been accelerating the expropriation of the peasants and caused a spectacular increase of the numbers of poor and tramps. The great capitalist magnates invested great amounts of money in financing wars, invasions and the development of military technology to broaden markets. The developments of Manufactures allowed to a colossal process of extraction of metals coming from the American continent.

 

Phases of emerging, rise and depletion of the Manufactures

 

The phase of emerging of Manufactures allowed for the application of intensive labour in the mines on the American continent and this allowed for a constant flow of precious metals and an increase of money reserves in Europe, which multiplied by four between the XVI and XVII. The silver extracted from the American continent between 1530 and 1650 reached 11 600 tons, that means, an annual average of 96 500 kg a year and as for gold, the amount extracted during XVI century was 153 561 kg, very important amount by XVI century standards.

 

This produced an increase of the amount of money in circulation for bankers used these reserves to develop emission of securities, papers and every kind of fictitious capital. With the boom phase of Manufactures, economy began to expand and European population accrued, overcoming the serious demographic crisis that had begun after the Hundred Years’ Wars when Europe suffered such diminishing of population that the cost of labour and salaries soared because there was no available labour.

 

The boom of Manufacturing has also allowed an agrarian expansion and recovery of mining activity. The slow recovery of population increased nearing XVII in 2/3, boosted the demand for food and all kinds of goods. A regime of accumulation was established with a pole of accumulation in the textile and mining industries. After the 80 Years’ War when Holland defeated Spain, the regime of accumulation of the Manufacture established the axis of accumulation in Holland and England.

 

By the XVII century, Manufacturing began the stage of depletion and this became manifest in the serious crises that crisis that erupted in all the economies as an outcome of the levelling and then the fall of the profit rate in Manufacturing, according to Engels, “… it always allows the manufacturer to produce at a lower cost than his outfashioned competitor, the craftsman… the same process is repeated: the surplus value he grabbed allows the manufacturing capitalist to sell not so expensive as his competitors until the generalisation of the new mode of production that spawns a new levelling.” (19)

 

The depletion of Manufacturing as a For of Accumulation caused a violent process of destruction of productive forces in the European countries as well as in the colonies. In Europe, the war between Holland and England broke out and that defined the predominance of England over Holland. This war was combined with the genocide in Africa, with the War of the Baltic and the civil war in England that culminated with the English Revolution led by Oliver Cromwell. With the bourgeoisie in power, England led the transition from a depleted Form of Accumulation, Manufacturing, to a superior one, Industry.

 

Manufacturing allowed great extraction of precious metals developed by Spain and, at the same time, it relied on this fabulous accumulation of capital for expansion in England and Holland. This is how Moreno explained it, “… If today, knowing everything that we already know, we had to write a course on Marxist political economy, it would be quite a bit more complex, richer… I would begin by saying that the process of original accumulation was a process not essentially English even if its centre was in England… The base of English original accumulation was not given by the proletariat but by raiding Spanish galleons. A great raid that fixed it all… they re-founded English capitalism with all this fabulous mass of surplus value that came from Latin America from the non-proletarian exploitation, from the Indians and the slaves.” (20)

 

The great mass of accumulated capital as precious material originated the great inflation of XVI century. It was studied by Hamilton and caused a great debate among economists and historians. It was called the “revolution of the prices” and was an inflationary process that took place in Europe in the XVI century, a process during which prices grew six-fold in 100 years. The XVI century was the outcome of 2 simultaneous processes: on the one hand, a fabulous mass of capital accumulated one of the most important in the history of capitalism.

 

This mass of capitals that accumulated consisted of the precious materials coming from America and the fictitious capital that rotated at terrific speed developed by the bankers in order to finance wars fleets, armies and the economic activity in general. But while this process was developing swiftly, the transition of Factories to Manufacturing was still in its infancy. i.e.: industrial production was still very poor and so was the development of the proletariat.

 

In the XVI century, the increase in the prices expressed an aspect of the Law of Value because the heaps of over-accumulated money needed valorising by means of human labour in the capitalist sense of the word. As manufacturing thrived, inflation of the prices began to dwindle following the accruing of salaried labour in Europe combined with the brutal exploitation of human labour accomplished by the manufacturing firms established on colonised continents where, even if there was salaried work, exploitation was based up to a great extent on slave labour. But this unevenness between the strong accumulation of capital based on exploitation of precious materials and the weakness of industrial development also caused the emergence of speculative bubbles in capitalism, ancestors of the speculative bubbles we can see today.

 

The surplus accumulation of fictitious capital was, in its turn, the base for inflation. States had to get deeply indebted in order to boost the armies and enterprises intended to consolidate Manufacturing. This need for the states and firms to obtain loans, led bankers to issue securities and debt papers that would finance the plans for commercial expansion. This impulse of papers, titles and loans of every kind boosted inflation by the state or “inflation of Benefits”, as Hamilton called it. Speculative bubbles like the one in Spain in 1557 and the one Tulip in Holland in 1634.

 

The “inflation of benefits” allowed for wages to be pushed down for they were quite high due to the lack of population after the War of the Hundred Years, but now wages grew no more for labour was abundant as the population accrued. IN this way, ensuring the general dwindling wages, capitalists could exploit human labour with the development of Manufacturing.

 

That is to say, the great inflation of the XVI is very similar to the great inflation developed before and during the globalisation regime between the XX and XXI centuries only expressing two diametrically opposed stage of capitalism. If the “great inflation of the XVII century” was part of the stage of birth of capitalism and expressed the first steps along the path of valorisation of capital developing production, the “great inflation of the XXI century” expresses its decadence and the increasing incapacity of capitalism to valorise capital by developing production.

 

5.  Commercial Ventures – colonising bourgeoisie’s Form of Accumulation

 

Commercial ventures are a Form of Accumulation constituted by societies of investors that achieve profit based on control of trade and exploitation of labour in the discovered colonies. From this point of view they are a more developed version of Trading Nations, but in this case, the Commercial ventures acted as a veritable state and government, carried out investments, developed manufacture and exploited local labour force and this allowed them to obtain enormous profit. These ventures were: The British Company of the East Indies, founded in 1600, The Dutch Company of the West Indies of 1602, The Danish Company of Eastern Indies of 1664, The Swedish Company of Eastern Indies, founded in 1731 and the Oostende Company. They were all founded by influential businessmen who would obtain the Royal Charter and exclusive permits to engage in trade with colonies for long periods of time.

 

The Commercial Ventures and Manufacturing developed in a joint and combined manner between XVI and XV centuries. As soon as the companies arrived at these colonies, they built the first manufacturing ventures. For example, The British Company of Eastern Indies had 23 factories in India and their profit was so great that they had to bribe kings and officials to prevent other ventures from landing and so be able to control the monopoly of economic activity in the zone. Great profits caused such great surplus accumulation of capital that in 1730, they spawned a speculative bubble of the South Sea Company in England.

 

These Companies were commercial ventures but they were also entitled to coin money, legislate, choose rulers and form armies of their own. For example, in 1670, King Charles II entitled the British Company of Eastern Indies to captain armies and form alliances, declare war or establish peace and exercise jurisdiction both civil and military within their operational territory. In 1689, the Company was practically a state inside India that administered Bombay, Madras and Bengal and possessed powerful military force. After the triumph over France, the British Company of Eastern Indies consolidated the monopoly of trade in India and went as far as controlling a fifth part of world’s population while the Dutch Company of Eastern Indies engulfed the entire Indonesian archipelago.

 

These forms of accumulation began in the early XVII century and by the end of the century the Commercial Ventures had started their process of depletion caused not only by the fall of the rate of profit but also and fundamentally due to the process of rebellion of the peoples against the imperial and colonialist oppression that put an end to the exploitation of the Companies. In India there was a massive revolt and popular revolution that in 1857 was called The Sepoy Mutiny and led to the dissolution of the most important of all those undertakings: The East Indies Company.

 

Transition from Manufacturing to Industry

 

When manufacturing was depleted, a violent process of destruction of productive forces through a complex of wars that included the War of the Thirty Years that occurred between 1618 and 1648 and the French-Spanish between 1635 and 1659, the wars between England and Holland between 1649 and 1660 and the Civil War in England, the latter actually was a deep revolutionary process in which bourgeoisie seized power in England and imposed a parliamentary political regime following the Dutch model.

 

The centre of all the conflagrations was the battle for the control of the manufacturing industry in Europe with epicentre in Holland-England and the manufacture established in the colonies. But there were also the wars fought by the Trading Ventures and the Anglo-Dutch Wars as well as the civil wars in England that were also part of the process of expropriating pre-capitalist social classes that was so characteristic of the process of Original Accumulation  of capitalism.

 

The process of expropriation engulfed the primitive tribes from the colonies living in original communism or Asiatic societies apart from the expropriation of peasants, sectors of nobility and even other sectors of bourgeoisie in continental Europe as well as in Wales, Scotland and Ireland. The War of the Thirty Years was fought between 1618 and 1648, mainly in the Germanic Holy Roman Empire, i.e.: what today is German territory in which most of the European powers of those days took part in order to grab hold of German and Italian enterprises  developed by the Hansa and Italy an the flourishing industries of both regions, apart from a serious clash between the nobility and the bourgeoisie in ascent and both continued their struggle for power.

 

Mercenaries were employed as a general rule in this war and the devastation of entire territories that were depleted by armies in need of supplies. The constant episodes of famine and epidemics decimated the civilian population of the German states and – up to a lesser degree – of the Netherlands and of Italy and led many of the implied powers to ruin. During those years the population of the Holy Empire was reduced in 30%.

 

In Brandenburg it was reduced by 50% and in some other regions to two thirds. Masculine population of Germany was reduced to half. In the Czech countries a third part of the population perished during the war as an outcome of famine, diseases and massive expulsion of Protestant Czechs. During that war, the Swedish armies alone destroyed 2000 castles, 18 000 villages, 15000 towns in Germany. The wars between England and Holland In the years between 1652 and 1666 involved all the economic powers of those days, such as France, Sweden, Spain, etc and ended in the defeat and decline of the predominance of Holland. The development of these wars allowed for a superior centralisation of capitals and for world supremacy of England that carried out the most important industrial revolution.

 

Both, England and Holland were commercial power with enormous fleets that dominated world commerce. But even if capitalism was going through the final stage of the original accumulation and the commercial capital still prevailed, it was these territories that were in the vanguard of the development of manufacturing and later on of Industry as Forms of accumulation that inaugurate the industrial state and the apogee of capitalism.

 

Based on the fabulous capital achieved through colonial exploitation and domination of the seas, Holland but above all England, could boost and finance the scientific discoveries to incorporate technology and new machines that gradually started displacing Manufacturing and initiated Industry. The booming development of industry was to drive England to displace Holland as a world power but at the cost of a brutal confrontation between the two powers and this implied enormous development of destructive forces.

 

The first Anglo-Dutch war took place between 1652 and 1654; the second was between 1665 and 1667 and ended with Dutch victories in the battle of the Four Days and Medway and the Third Anglo Dutch war between 1672 and 1674 and a front in which England joined France against Holland. The civil wars in England developed between 1642 and 1689. The first civil war in the years1642-1645 was a confrontation between the parliament and the royalty where Parliament won and eliminated the Court from the Star Chamber and executed William Laud, Archbishop of Canterbury and Count Strafford, an important ally of the king.

 

During the second English civil war between 1648 and 1649, Cromwell repressed the rebellion in Wales and defeated the Scots in Preston, defeated the royalists, executed king Charles I and proclaimed English Republic. With the third English civil war, between 1649 and 1651 annihilated the royalists in Ireland and Scotland and controlled England. At the same time, wars between companies broke out, for example: the English with the Dutch and Portuguese in the zone of the Indic Ocean after which the British Company of the Western Indies consolidated the monopoly of trade in the zone.

 

  • Forms of Accumulation specific to the Stage of the Apogee of Capitalism

 

Insofar as that the capitalist mode of production became dominant and definitely displaced the feudal mode of production and also insofar as the bourgeoisie was conquering the power of the state we entered the stage of the apogee of capitalist mode of production that engulfs the XVIII and XIX centuries up to early XX century. This stage began after the triumph of 3 great revolutions: the 1648 English revolution led by Oliver Cromwell, the 1776 American Revolution and the 1789 French Revolution.

Capitalism boosted the production, trade and finances sweeping away all the previous social formations and pre-capitalist modes of production and reached its zenith of its development as an economic, political and social system. At this stage of the apogee of capitalism, the predominant Forms of Accumulation are: industry in the scope of production and the Credit Banks in the scope of finances; we shall now analyze that now.

 

1. Industry: Form of Accumulation of industrial bourgeoisie      

            

Industry is the Form of Accumulation emerged in the XVIII, when the capitalist incorporates machines to the factory where he groups workers. Labour division combined with machines that replaced manual labour gave room for series production, increased productivity of labour and the exploitation of labour and consequently industry implied a leap in the process of accumulation of capital and profit. The modern salaried proletariat surfaces in industry and the capitalist mode of production is consolidated with its two fundamental social classes: the proletariat and the bourgeoisie.

 

This process began in 1735, when John Wyatt announced his spinning machine that revolutionised the textile industry. But the introduction of machines also allowed a revolution in the production and trade because it revolutionised transport and communications. In the early days of industry, the most important technological innovations were the steam machined and what was known as Spinning Jenny, related to textile industry, but hot on their heels there came other machines and technologies and were a permanent improvement of the process of production. We include all farming and countryside production as well as all the production at sea, such a fishing and raw materials are included here.

 

Even if they move in different conditions, such as the outcome of the land revenue in the case of the countryside, as industry developed, the process of expropriation of small owners and as machinery was introduced in the countryside revolutioning the entire production the entire production was finally absorbed by industry and became just another variant of the industrial Forms of Accumulation. That is how the landownership became consolidated.

 

In 1713, after the wars of the XVII century, the Utrecht Treaty consolidated the domination of England that became the axis of the accumulation and new industries cropped up, such as chemistry, electricity or car industry together with the development of new forms of energy such as gas or oil. Industry spread on to other countries such as Germany, Russia, the USA, Japan, the Netherlands and a so far unprecedented scientific revolution accrued.

 

The phase of the emergence of industry coincided with the apogee of the capitalist mode of production and this allowed for a steady expansion of economy. But the revolutionary character in the production means that industry also developed all the contradictions of capitalism much more intensively. But we shall analyse this in chapter 6.

 

During the industrial boom, the levelling of the interest rate only that now this process developed much faster. This is how Engels explained it, “…industry, that due to the endless revolution in the production increasingly reduces the costs of production of goods… on the other hand it levels the rate of profit of the different branches of commercial and industrial business reducing it to a sole general rate of profit and, due to this levelling, makes sure that industry maintains a position of strength that corresponds to it by eliminating all the obstacles that up to that moment prevented the transfer of capitals from one branch to the other.” (21)

 

In the early XIX century, industries began to enter their phase of depletion, and this unleashed a new and violent wave of wars and revolutions. Industry produced a rapid development that collided with internal customs and social formations inherited from feudalism and that is why the revolutions and civil wars that pushed bourgeoisie to power were followed by new revolutions and civil wars in which bourgeoisie eliminated internal customs, broadened the home market, imposed national frontiers and so the modern states emerged.

 

With the 1848 revolutions, modern capitalist national states emerged. These wars and revolutions were in 1848 in France, Italy, Germany, in the Austro-Hungarian Empire and the American civil war o 1862. All this process of destruction of productive forces cleared the path for a higher Form of Accumulation: monopolies, the outcome of the fact that these wars and revolutions of 1848 as well as American civil war allowed the development of the countries, national unity and home market.

 

With the emergence of countries and home market Forms of Accumulation that allowed the dominion of a branch of production within the scope of a country, monopolies, trusts and cartels to control and this spawned the entrance of capitalism into its highest and final stage of decadence, the imperialist stage.

 

2. Banks and Credit – Form of Accumulation of Financial Bourgeoisie

 

During the days of apogee of capitalism Banks and Credit developed as a Form of Accumulation of financial capital and these institutions comprise the modern banking system. Even though both had antecedents with the first Banks in Genoa and Venice with the development of the Trading Nations, are the real expression of the capitalist mode of production and turned the old demands of the bourgeoisie against usury and merchants who monopolised financial capital during the entire period of primitive accumulation.

 

Credit was born by reaction against usury, a Form of Accumulation that, together with the banks expressed the beginning of the consolidation of the mode of capitalist production. According to Marx, “The development of the credit is carried out as a reaction against usury… I means precisely the subordination of the capital that produces interest to the conditions and needs of capitalist production. According to Marx, “The development of credit occurs by reaction against usury… It means precisely subordination of interest-producing capital to the conditions and needs of capitalist mode of production… it is the starting point of the modern credit system. Credit associations, constituted in Venice and Genoa in the XII and XIV centuries, were spawned by the need of overseas trade and the wholesale trade based on it, of getting rid of the domination of the methods of aged methods of usury and monopolisers of the trade of money” (22)

 

It was precisely the dominating class of financial tycoons get busy founding banks that emit debt bonds and distribute credit while being part of the State that emerges from the functioning of the Banks and boosts their functioning. This class is born inextricably linked to the State and the state to this class of capitalists, just as Marx explained, “Even though banks as such, founded in these republics are regarded at the same time as establishments of public credit that anticipated money for the State on taxes to be collected, we must never forget that these associations the notables of the above mentioned states that the merchants who constituted these associations were at the same time the notables of the afore mentioned states and had the same interest in liberating their state from usury as in getting rid of it themselves and at the same time to assert and reinforce the submission they had with respect to the State“ (23)

 

This is the way Karl Marx explains it, “this violent attack against usury, this demand of submitting the interest producing capital to industrial capital is nothing but the harbinger of the organic creations that, in the modern banking system, establish the conditions of capitalist production: on the one hand, banks deprive usury capital of its monopoly by concentrating all the idle - dead-like - reserves and launching them on to financial market and, on the other hand, limit the monopoly of precious metals and crating credit money” (24)

 

 In 1694, six years after the revolution headed by Oliver Cromwell, Bank of England became the first officially acknowledged bank. Just as Bank of France, Bank of England did not start as a state-owned bank or as a crown enterprise; it was a private bank, controlled by the Rotschild clan, the European banking dynasty that managed the finances of England, France, Germany, Austria and Italy, together with associates Khun, Loeb, Lehman, Warburg, etc. The Bank of England was nationalised in 1946, after the end of World War II, at the beginning of the Keynesian regime; the same as Bank of France.

      

             If the industrial production revolutionised all the aspects of production and achieved an all but unprecedented mass of goods but at the same time, credit soon developed tendencies to concentration and centralisation of capitals and left thousands smaller capitals in ruins. And this allowed great capitals to expropriate lesser capitals and allowed centralisation of capitals.         

            

Credit was born as a rejection of usury, a Form of Accumulation that, together with a Charles Marx explained the role of credit, “It does not only turn into a new and powerful weapon in the competitive struggle. By means of invisible threads, it draws money resources that, in larger or smaller masses, are dispersed all over the surface of society towards the hands of individual or

associated capitalists. It is specific machinery for the concentration of capitals… credit…. A new and terrible weapon in the competitive struggle and finally becomes immense social mechanism for

centralising capitals … just as capitalist production and accumulation develop, so do competition and credit, the two most powerful tools of centralisation.” (25)

 

            The increasing centralisation of capital that credit and Banks boosted the base of the formation of monopolies, carters and trusts that cleared the path for the stage of decadence of capitalism: the imperialist stage, when financial capital began to prevail over the industrial stage.

 

            This is the way Frederic Engels explained it, “…these changes tend to concentrate all stock speculators, all the industrial and farming production, commerce as a whole as well as the means of communication and organisms of exchange so that the Stock Exchange becomes the most eminent representative of the capitalist production itself. In 1865 the Stock Exchange was still a second rate element in capitalist system… things are different today. Even since the 1866 crisis accumulation has been increasingly gaining speed…”

 

            “… There is still progressive transformation in industry in stock companies. All the branches, one after the other, yield to this fate… mining, steel and iron industry, chemical industry and textile industry… the same goes for commerce… the same within the farming scope. Banks increasingly turn into mortgage creditors. If this goes on, is possible to predict that all English and French lands will fall into the hands of the Stock Exchange. Finally, all the investments abroad are made as share…” (26)

 

C- Forms of Accumulation specific to the stage of Decadence of Capitalism

Fusion of Forms of productive and financial Accumulation

 

The Forms of Accumulation corresponding to the imperialist stage or the stage of decadence of capitalism are Monopolies, Multinationals and finally Multinational Corporations. You will find our analysis corresponding to these Forms of Accumulation in chapters III and IV, together with the analysis of the political- social mechanisms that allowed for the passage from one Form of Accumulation to the other.

 

General Conclusions  

 

The mechanism by means of which the passage from one Form of Accumulation to another, superior Form of Accumulation is through a violent process of destruction of productive forces. Marx worked out the laws of accumulation of capital that explain how this process develops from the economic point of view; what still remained how this was done in combination with the political and social factors. The process of destruction of productive forces required for the centralisation and accumulation of capital implied permanent destruction and liquidation of social classes and sectors of classes through wars and revolutions.

 

In this way, the laws that explain the passage from one Form of Accumulation to a superior one link the laws of Marxist economics to historical materialism. The mechanism of annihilation and burning of capitals that capitalism developed to solve their crises and make headway in the forms of accumulation and centralisation of capitals is explained fundamentally by the role of private property and social classes.

 

Property of means of production and exchange spawns bourgeoisie as a dominating class with the different sectors of the bourgeois class who are in permanent dispute over capitals and profits. Behind the trading nations, factories, industries, manufactures, monopolies and multinationals there is the social class that owns these different means of production and different sectors of this dominant class.

 

It is the struggle in defence private property, interests and profits what explains the reason for which capitalism evolves in different Forms of Accumulation. The different Forms of Accumulation are surpassed and transformed; for example, monopolies still exist but are surpassed and contained in the multinationals. The whole process of evolution of the forms of accumulation was gradually deposited on one another as we can see in geological layers.

 

In the development of this mechanism we can observe behind each violent process of destruction of productive forces there has always been a new centralisation of capitals that permitted a superior Form of Accumulation and a period of long expansion of capitalist economy. With the depletion, the period of expansion comes to an end and a long period of stagnation of economy and that inevitably leads to a new process of destruction of productive forces.

 

Periods of long expansion or of long stagnation have lasted for different amount of time. Sometimes they lasted for barely a decade and on other occasion they lasted for 60 or 70 years and sometimes even more than that. But these periods can be explained by the phenomenon of the emergence of a new Form of Accumulation and its rise, and that is what explain the long periods of expansion of capitalist economy.

 

On the contrary, the depletion of the Forms of Accumulation is what explains the long periods of stagnation. Two types of crises combine permanently and dialectically: the small crises, chronic, systematic, part of a regular development of capitalism with the longer crises, as we shall see in the following chapter- This happens due to the fact that regular crises happen always either in the framework of a period of stagnation or in a period of expansion. These periods are determined by the rise or stagnation of the predominant Forms of Accumulation.

 

The General Law of the Forms of Accumulation allows us understand more fully the development of the crisis of capitalism and allows us to overcome the old schemas such as the old opinion that capitalism in its apogee kept on developing productive forces for a long time and then, during its decadence, only developed destructive forces. With the General Law of the Forms of Accumulation, this scheme is definitely overcome. It is now clear that capitalism has alternated between the development of productive forces and destructive forces in all its phases and that the engine economy and of overcoming one Form of Accumulation to go to the next is the development of the destructive forces and of the war.

 

Nahuel Moreno anticipated some of these conclusions in his last courses of economy and he evidenced doubts as to the progressive character of capitalism, as to whether throughout its history, capitalism evolved in a contradictory manner with the development of productive forces. This is the way he expressed it, “I have my doubts… if capitalism has not always been a contradictory phenomenon that developed technology and annihilated nature and man and whether it is not a permanent law of capitalism… These are my personal doubts… I am terribly worried about the numbers of Indians and the numbers of African Negroes massacred by capitalism in the XVI century and XVII century; I mean… some of the estimates are lurid. Almost 90% of the native population was annihilated in 50 years… So I do not know if it is not that capitalism has a permanently pernicious face against the development of productive forces… From the very beginning, it was very progressive from the point of view of technology in the period of great technical development, but objectively it has been leading to barbarism. That is to say, what we are witnessing now is not the consequence of a great wonder that changed and became bad; it was evil from the very beginning and now it is becoming more and more evil…”

 

“My doubt is whether it all began with imperialism… or whether it began when capitalism arrived… for it is the first system of production that does not work for consumption that from the word go is such an irrational thing that it goes against productive forces from the very beginning. Technically, it is the one that most develops precisely because it does not produce for consumption. But at the same time it is the one that most destroys nature, it obliterates everything from the beginning. And today it is the monstrosity of a law that has been permanent.” (27)

 

Notes

 

             (1) & (2) Karl Marx: The Capital, First Book, chapter XXIII. The General Law of Capitalist Accumulation

 

             (3) & (4) Frederic Engels: Supplement and Complement for Book III of Capital

 

             (5) & (6) Perry Anderson: Transitions from Antiquity to Feudalism; Second Part 4 Feudal dynamics

 

             (8), (9), (10) & (11) Frederic Engels. Supplement and Complement of Book III of the Capital

 

            (12) Nahuel Moreno – Cuatro Tesis sobre la colonización española y portuguesa

 

            (13), (14) & (15) Reyna Pastor de Togneri:  Historia del Movimiento Obrero. Capítulo I Artesanos y Campesinos en crisis

 

            (16) Perry Anderson: Transitions from Antiquity to Feudalism; Second Part 4 Feudal dynamics

 

            (17) Alberto J. Plá - Historia del Movimiento Obrero. Introducción

 

            (18) Karl Marx. The Capital, First Book, chapter 12; Division of labour and manufacturing

 

            (19) Frederic Engels: Supplement and Complements to Book III of the Capital

 

            (20) Nahuel Moreno: School of Economy 1984

 

            (21) Frederic Engels; Supplement and Complement to Book III of the Capital

 

            (22), (23) & (24) Karl Marx, The Capital; Third Book, chapter 36, Notes on the pre-capitalist period

 

            (25) Karl Marx, The Capital, First Book, chapter XXIII, General Law of Capitalist Accumulation

 

            (26) Frederic Engels, Supplement and Complement to Book III of The Capital

 

            (27) Nahuel Moreno: School of Economy 1984

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 


 

([1]) Mita was a compulsory public service agrarian, mining, domestic service, etc. Native inhabitants, especially in the Andean region were assigned to the premises where they worked in semi enslaved condition. 

 

([2]) Encomienda existed when the crown assigned a certain number of aborigines to a Spanish subject known as encomendero, in consideration of services rendered

bottom of page